Business Management Articles / Manufacturing
Management
TECHNOLOGY ACQUISITION- NOT TECHNOLOGY
TRANSFER
by Rene T.
Domingo (email comments to rtd@aim.edu)
Japanese direct
investment in developing countries especially in
Asia brings in capital inflows, employment, and
technology to the region. As Japan invest in and
divest from the region, the first two come and
go with the investment, while technology
continues to have a lasting impact on the host
country development long after the investment is
gone.
While thre
receiving nations have sophisticated
infrastructures, policies, and institutions to
monitor and control foreign capital inflow and
outflow and the resulting employment or
unemployment levels, no similar concern have
been given to the inflow of foreign technology,
its nurture, and indigenization. The only
existing controls on technology transfer in the
region are of the quantitative and financial
type: number and length of stay foreign experts,
tariffs on equipment, repatriation of royalty
payments, tax incentives and disincentives.
Practically none exists on the kind,
appropriateness, adaptability, and development
impact of incoming foreign technology. The
technology transfer bodies of several develping
Asian economies only have limited police role of
screening out restrictive clauses from foreign
technology licensing agreements. Most ASEAN
governments grant incentives, including
citizenship or permanent resident status, to
foreign investors who bring with them a
specified amount of foreign capital and generate
a certain level of local employment, with little
or no regard to the technology they bring in. On
the other hand, the South Korea and Taiwan,
invite and screen foreign investors mainly on
the technology they would introduce in to the
country.
Japan, in her
early days in industrialization, selectively
encouraged foreign investment on the basis of
its technological inputs, rather than capital
inflows or employment. The only condition was
that the foreigners be allowed to be taken over
by the local businessmen as soon as the latter
had mastered their technology. If the needed
technology could be obtained by other means such
as inviting foreign experts for a short term but
at high cost , or sending some Japanese abroad
to study, or licensing agreements- foreign
investment, which reduced Japan's economic
independence, was avoided as much as possible.
Japan's
technological superiority started with copying
of foreign technology, reverse engineering, and
marketing the cloned product to compete with the
West. Similarly, the Koreans and Taiwanese are
copying Japanese products and eating into
Japan's own market's in the process. Innovation
is not the most important step in technology
transfer. Developing countries deplore the fact
that Japanese companies are not doing R & D or
developing new products in their overseas
subsidiaries in the region. Their small domestic
markets can not justify such expensive
activities. Many developing countries mistakenly
equate innovation with technology and
industrialization. As shown by Japan, Korea, and
other newly industriliazed nations,
industrialization does not start with
innovation. Export markets are not initially
conquered with new products and technology.
Develping countries in Asia and other regions
are not exempt from this natural course in
industrial development.
The main question
in selecting the type of technology to be
transferred is whether it is consistent with the
industrial development needs of the host country
at the time of the transfer. However, most
Japanese direct foreign investment decisions are
made on the basis of the global strategy of the
Japanese multinationals and trading companies.
Technology transfer considerations, much less
its appropriateness to the host country
development, have the lowest priority in their
investment decisions. There are reported
instances of overly sophisticated and automated
machines which companies in the receiving
nations cannot operate, old and inefficient
labor-intensive equipment , or hardware that
will not endure the region's climate and
humidity. This problem can be minimized if
developing countries would make technology a
major criterion in screening potential Japanese
investors to the region.
Another important
issue is whether developing countries needs
"hardware" technology more than "software"
technology considering the region's current
stage of development. The former, often
preferred in the form of the latest, fastest,
and most efficient equipment and systems, does
not always guarantee improved or more profitable
operations. Overemphasis on hardware has led to
losses in many local firms due to
underutilization of capacities or expensive
downtime. Without paying any royalty, local
companies stand to gain more by adopting the
Japanese "software' or "management" technologies
- techniques in operations management, human
resource management, quality control,
subcontracting, machine maintenance, and other
useful productivity techniques. Developing
countries have a major deficiency and weakness
in quality control which limit their export
capabilities. This technology could be freely
acquired from Japan. Even non-Japanese companies
in the region which have adopted the Japanese
Total Quality technology and some features of
Just-in-time production control have reported
gains in profits and productivity .
Japan does not
have adequate skills for technology transfer. It
is a necessary art receiving nations must
develop. The phrase "technology transfer" is
inaccurate for it implies that the technology
supplier has the initiative to transfer the
technology while the recipient or the party
which needs it just waits for the transfer to
take place. The donor of technology is normally
an indifferent party in the technology transfer
process since it stands to gain minimally if not
at all from it, unless technology itself is the
main merchandise it is selling. "Technology
acquisition", a more appropriate and useful term
for developing countries to employ, connotes a
more active role on the part of the recipient.
It also means that the technology supplier,
Japan, may naturally stay passive while the
receiving countries determines the technology it
needs, negotiates with the supplier, and
initiates the "acquisition" process. If the
roles are reserved, the supplier will often
provide the wrong technology and dictate the
terms of the transfer process unilaterally.
Governments of
developing countries should set targets for
technologies to be acquired and developed and
make these national priorities of the same
importance as GNP, balance of payments, balance
of trade, and other economic indicators.
|